Explaining Acemoglu's model of directed technical change: a primer

Sat Apr 20 2019

tags: academic economics macroeconomics explanation public draft

Table of contents

  1. Introduction and nontechnical explanation of the paradox
  2. We can solve the paradox by directed technical change
  3. But why would technical change be directed? Market effects
  4. Implications of the model, and comparisons to other models:
    • Schumpeterian-Solow model

Introduction and nontechnical explanation

I first want to begin with a seeming paradox. Call this The Paradox. Consider these two facts:

  1. The number of highly-skilled workers has increased greatly over the past few decades.
  2. The skill premium[1] has increased despite a huge increase in high-skilled workers.

This seems counterintuitive. We know the labour market is determined by supply and demand. Therefore, it seems like the skill premium should decrease. We must conclude that something is making the skill premium go up despite the large influx of high-skilled workers.

What could it be? The answer is directed technical change: despite the fact that there are much more high-skilled workers nowadays, high-skilled workers have become much more productive than low-skilled ones, and therefore they command a higher wage.

But why have high-skilled workers become much more productive than low-skilled ones? Here's one possibility.

The nature of technological progress this few decades (e.g. computer, microchips) has been more suited for high-skilled workers.

At first glance, this explanation seems plausible. But if you think about it, it falls apart. See Acemoglu:

At the expense of oversimplifying, we can say that the microchip could have been used to develop advanced scanners that would increase the productivity of unskilled workers, or advanced computer-assisted machines that would be used by skilled workers to replace unskilled workers. (p.31)

In other words, technology itself does not confer disproportionate benefits on either group: what matters are the innovations that build upon that technological breakthrough.

The large increase in the number of high-skilled workers has made it more profitable for innovators to develop technologies that boost their productivity.

The real reason for directed technical change is actually a market size effect. Innovators focus their efforts on developing technologies that maximise their profit, and how much they can sell their R&D for depends on how many people use their technology. The more high-skilled workers there are, the more innovators develop for them, and the larger their productivity grows. This nicely turns the supply-and-demand story on its head, and gives us our answer to the paradox.

Here, I present Acemoglu's model of directed technical change, that formalises all we've just talked about. Why Acemoglu's model specifically?

  1. It is the only model in Oxford's macroeconomics course that talks about directed technical change/ high- vs low-skilled workers.
  2. It nicely explains The Paradox.

Review questions

What was the empirical motivation for Acemoglu's model of directed technological change?

How can the skill premium go up even as the relative supply of high-skilled workers goes up?

Formalising the paradox

The production function, as well as our utility function, is given by

Y=[(AHH)ρ+(ALL)ρ]1ρY = [(A_H H)^\rho + (A_L L)^\rho]^{1-\rho}

There are high-skilled goods produced by high-skilled labour, and low-skilled goods produced by low-skill labour. We will ignore capital. Note here that this is a CRS production function.

We shall first disregard the technology growth function (how AHA_H and ALA_L change over time).

Because this is a competitive market, workers are paid their marginal productivities:

wLMPL=ALρ[ALρ+AHρ(HL)ρ]1ρρw_L \equiv MPL = A^\rho_L \left[A^\rho_L + A^\rho_H\left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^\rho\right]^\frac{1-\rho}{\rho}

wHMPH=AHρ[ALρ(HL)ρ+AHρ]1ρρw_H \equiv MPH = A^\rho_H \left[A^\rho_L \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^{-\rho} + A^\rho_H\right]^\frac{1-\rho}{\rho}

Combining these two equations we get the skill premium ω\omega:

ωwHwL=(AHAL)ρ(HL)(1ρ)\omega \equiv \frac{w_H}{w_L} = \left(\frac{A_H}{A_L}\right)^\rho \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^{-(1-\rho)}

=(AHAL)(σ1)/σ(HL)(1σ)= \left(\frac{A_H}{A_L}\right)^{(\sigma-1)/\sigma} \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^{-(\frac{1}{\sigma})}

where σ\sigma is the elasticity of substitution[2]:

σ11ρ\sigma \equiv \frac{1}{1-\rho}

Taking logs on both sides gives

lnω=σ1σln(AhAl)1σln(HL)\ln \omega = \frac{\sigma-1}{\sigma} \ln(\frac{A_h}{A_l}) - \frac{1}{\sigma}\ln(\frac{H}{L})

Let's take a look at this last equation, and plot it in a graph with x-axis HL\frac{H}{L}. We can see that as the number of skilled workers increases (HH \uparrow), the lower the wage premium.

An increase in skilled workers causes a decrease in the wage
premium

An increase in skilled workers (HHH^{*} \rightarrow H') leads to a decrease in wage premium (movement from ABA \rightarrow B).

Review questions

What is the production function stated by Acemoglu?

What is the skill premium?

What is the elasticity of substitution? How does it relate to \(\rho\)?


Solving the paradox by directed technical change

We have just formalised the result that as the relative ratio of high-skilled workers increases, the wage premium decreases. This is great, but how then can we explain the empirical finding that the skill premium ω\omega has increased over the decades? The answer is a combination of both elasticity of substitution σ\sigma and a skill-biased technical change. Looking once again at the previous equation, we see that ω\omega can increase if the term

σ1σln(AhAl)\frac{\sigma-1}{\sigma} \ln(\frac{A_h}{A_l})

increases.

Under what circumstances will this term increase? Well, one way is to increase AhA_h. But an increase in AhA_h will only increase this term if σ>1\sigma > 1. If workers are not very substitutable (σ<1\sigma < 1), an improvement in the productivity of skilled workers reduces the skill premium. This case appears paradoxical at first but is in fact quite intuitive. As Acemoglu says:

Consider, for example, a Leontieff (fixed proportions) production function. In this case, when AhA_h increases and skilled workers become more productive, the demand for unskilled workers, who are necessary to produce more output by working with the more productive skilled workers, increases by more than the demand for skilled workers. In some sense, in this case, the increase in AhA_h is creating an “excess supply” of skilled workers given the number of unskilled workers. This excess supply increases the unskilled wage relative to the skilled wage.

Okay. So suppose σ>1\sigma > 1. Then, an increase in AhA_h will indeed increase the wage premium by shifting the line upwards.

Skill-biased technology change can offset an increase in skilled labour,
causing the wage labour to increase

Figure 2 illustrates. Despite the increase in H/L, skill-biased technology change causes the wage premium to increase from ww^* to ww^{**}.

Great---we have solved the paradox by introducing skill-biased technical change. More explicitly, the relative productivity of skilled workers,

(Ah/Al)σ1σ,(A_h/A_l)^\frac{\sigma-1}{\sigma},

must have increased.

Acemoglu's model with endogenous directed technical change.

I've just shown that one can have an increase in the ratio of high- to low- skilled workers IF the coefficient of substitution σ>1\sigma > 1 AND technical change is directed towards high-skilled workers.

But that begs the questions: why was technical change directed towards high-skilled workers? Now we attempt to endogenise technical change (i.e. try and find a reason within the model why technical change was directed).

We have our utility/production function once again:

Y=[(AHH)ρ+(ALL)ρ]1ρY = [(A_H H)^\rho + (A_L L)^\rho]^{1-\rho}

Here, let's introduce some innovators. Innovators can produce innovations, AHA_H or ALA_L, that increase the productivity of all high- or low-skill workers. Let the fixed cost of producing an innovation be B and let the marginal cost of producing the new technology be 0. Then the marginal benefit of providing a new technology is simply the marginal increase in productivity (HH or LL) multiplied by the price of that good; this gives pHHp_H H and pLLp_L L respectively.

We can see that innovators will only choose to produce an innovation if they stand to make a profit: in other words only when B<pHHB < p_H H.

Here, there are two factors that affect innovation: price and market size.

Price effect: the larger the price of the good pHp_H, the more profit innovators stand to make.

Market size effect: The more high- or low- skilled workers HH, the more profit innovators stand to make.

There is a further equilibrium condition. At equilibrium, the marginal benefit of providing both high- and low- skilled technologies must be equal. Otherwise, people would start developing more technologies of the other one to make more profit.

This gives us the following condition:

phH=plLp_h H = p_l L

By consumer optimisation,

pHpL=MUHMUL\frac{p_H}{p_L} = \frac{MU_H}{MU_L}

After all, consider the case where LHS > RHS. Then, it would be a Pareto improvement to substitute 1 unit of H for 1 unit of L.

But we know here that the production and utility functions are the same! Thus,

MUH==MPHMU_H == MPH

and

MUL=MPL.MU_L = MPL.

Therefore, we can reuse the previous result

pHpL=[AHHALL]ρ1\frac{p_H}{p_L} = \left [ \frac{A_H H}{A_L L} \right ] ^{\rho-1}

Substituting in the equilibrium condition, and replacing $$\sigma = 1/(1- \rho)$$ gives us

AhAl=(HL)σ1\frac{A_h}{A_l} = \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^ {\sigma - 1}

This gives the result that when σ>1\sigma > 1, more technology will be produced for the higher-skilled worker if H/L increases (i.e. the market size effect dominates). In other words --- directed technical progress! This is something we previously assumed in the exogenous case, but now we have shown how directed technical progress is in fact caused by a large supply of high-skilled workers.

Okay, we've shown that if σ>1\sigma > 1, when HH \uparrow, AHAL\frac{A_H}{A_L} \uparrow. But what about the skill premium?

ωwHwL=(AHAL)ρ(HL)(1ρ)\omega \equiv \frac{w_H}{w_L} = \left(\frac{A_H}{A_L}\right)^\rho \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^{-(1-\rho)}

Substituting the result we got for AhAl\frac{A_h}{A_l} into the equation, as well as the fact that σ11ρ\sigma \equiv \frac{1}{1-\rho}, we obtain

=(HL)σ2= \left(\frac{H}{L}\right)^{\sigma-2}

This result tells us that if σ>2\sigma > 2, then an increase in relative supply of high-skilled workers increases the skill premium. Note that this is different from the exogenous model. In the exogenous model, as long as $$\sigma > 1$$ both the level of skill-biased technology and the skill premium increase. In the endogenous model, if 1<σ<21 < \sigma < 2 the level of technology does increase, but the skill premium actually decreases (the increase in supply outweighs the increase in technology).

Level of σ\sigma Exogenous model Endogenous model
0<σ<10 < \sigma < 1 ω\omega \downarrow ALA_L \uparrow ω\omega \downarrow ALA_L \uparrow
1<σ<21 < \sigma < 2 ω\omega \uparrow AHA_H \uparrow ω\omega \downarrow AHA_H \uparrow
σ>2\sigma > 2 ω\omega \uparrow AHA_H \uparrow ω\omega \uparrow AHA_H \uparrow

Comparison to other models

In the Schumpeter-Solow case, demand for innovation is gotten from k^\hat{k}, level of capital per effective labour unit. The greater k^\hat{k} is, the more profit innovators stand to make.

TODO

Conclusion

TODO


  1. The wage premium ω\omega, is defined as wHwL\frac{w_H}{w_L}. ↩︎

  2. How do we get the elasticity of substitution?? How is it defined? TODO ↩︎